In the long run, perfectly competitive firms produce a level of output such that:

8b - PURE COMPETITION - LONG RUN EQUILIBRIUM AND EFFICIENCY

From Short-run to Long-run in Perfectly Competitive Markets (econclassroom.com 21:23)
http://www.econclassroom.com/?p=3018
Why a firm in a perfectly competitive market will only earn normal profits (zero economic profits) in the long run.

Review:

  • In a perfectly competitive market the market supply and market demand determine the price and marginal revenue for each individual firm in that market
  • for each individual firm the demand is perfectly elastic at the market price and the marginal revenue will be equal to the price
  • two graphs: one for the market and one for the individual firm
    • supply and demand curves for the whole market which includes all of the individual firms
    • graph for the individual firm includes:
      • D=P=MR
      • MC
      • AVC
      • ATC (per unit cost of the firm's output)
  • the profit maximizing quantity for the individual firm will occur where MR = MC
  • The equilibrium quantity in the market will be equal to the profit maximizing quantity for the individual firms times the number of firms
  • The video shows a graph where a firm is breaking even and economic profits = zero
    • TR minus TC = zero
    • the firm is earning a normal profit which means that its total revenue (TR) is enough to just equal all of its explicit costs AND the implicit costs of paying the entrepreneur (owner) a salary to keep him/her in business

    In the long run, perfectly competitive firms produce a level of output such that:

Long Run Equilibrium

A normal profit (zero economic profits) is what we would expect individual firms in a perfectly competitive market to earn in the long run because there are no barriers to entry.

And in long run equilibrium the P = MC (allocative efficiency, more later) and P = minimum ATC (productive efficiency, more later).

The individual firms are producing the quantity where their costs per unit (the ATC) are the lowest.

if the firms produce any other quantity (less or more) then the costs per unit (ATC) will be higher than the price and they would earn economic losses [ME: meaning that they could make more by quitting this business and going to their next best alternative.]

Why do perfectly competitive firms only earn a normal profit in the long run?

  • What if they are earning short run profits due to an increase in demand for their product?
    • on the market graph the market demand will shift to the right resulting in higher equilibrium market price
    • on the graph for the individual firm the higher market price is shown as a shift upwards of their perfectly elastic D= P curve which is also their MR curve (D=P=MR)
    • each individual firm then will respond to the higher market price by producing a higher quantity since they will always try to maximize their profits by producing where MR = MC, and this now occurs at a higher level of output
    • this higher price and quantity for each individual firm will result in short run economic profits
      • ME: with the higher price and quantity its total revenue (TR) will be a lot higher
      • its total costs (TC) will be only a little higher. Note the ATC curve does not shift, but rather as firms increase output they move slightly up their existing ATC curves
      • and the yellow rectangle represents the firms new short run profits caused by an increase in market demand

        In the long run, perfectly competitive firms produce a level of output such that:

    • But, what will happen in the long run?
      • these short run economic profits will attract new firms to the industry. REMEMBER: in pure competition there are no barriers to entry so new firms can easily enter the industry to try to capture some of these economic profits.
      • so, what will happen to our graphs if new firms enter?
        • one of the non-price determinants of supply is the number of producers. If the number of producers goes up, then the market supply will increase and shift to the left.
        • this will cause the market price to fall and the P=D=MR curve for the individual firms to fall
        • the individual firms then will no longer be earning short run profits and in the long run they will be back to zero, or normal, profits
        • Entry Eliminates Profits

        In the long run, perfectly competitive firms produce a level of output such that:

      • ME: so what has happened in this perfectly competitive industry in response to an increase in demand?
        • Earlier we said: "The equilibrium quantity in the market will be equal to the profit maximizing quantity for the individual firms times the number of firms"
        • because of the increase in demand and the increase in supply that resulted from it the equilibrium quantity in the market has increased from Qe to Qe2 on the graph above.
        • each individual firm is still producing the same quantity as before (Qf) after temporarily producing a larger quantity
        • But, there are now more firms in the industry each producing QF at the original price of Pe.
        • This is good for consumers (society) . We wanted more (increase in demand) and we got more at the same price.
  • What if they are earning short run losses due to a decrease in demand for their product?
    • Assume that initially all individual firms are earning zero (normal) profits
    • if demand decreases the market demand curve will shift to the left and the equilibrium price will fall
    • for the individual firms this means that their D-P- MR curve will shift downward
    • firms always want to maximize their profits so they will produce the quantity where MR=MC, which is now at a lower quantity
    • and at this new profit maximizing quantity the price is now below their ATC and they will now be earning economic losses.
      • price is lower, so TR is lower
      • ATC is now higher
      • so their ATC is now > P
        • ME: Price (P) and Average Revenue (AR) mean the same thing
      • and Profits = TR - TC = will be negative (economic losses)

    • How will firms respond to these short run economic losses?
      • Exit Eliminates Losses
      • due to the short run losses some firms will leave the industry
        • remember an economic loss means that they can make more at their next best alternative
        • and since there are no barriers to entry or EXIT, it is easy for firms to leave and go to their next best alternative
      • this will decrease the number of producers and decrease the market supply
      • causing the equilibrium market price to increase
      • for each individual firms this will shift their D = P = MR curve upward
      • and they will respond by producing where MR = MC which will be at a higher quantity and they will be earning normal (zero) profits again

        In the long run, perfectly competitive firms produce a level of output such that:

    • after all adjustments the price will again be equal to the minimum ATC, where the MC crosses the ATC
    • and P = ATC = MC
  • ME: So, in the long run in a perfectly competitive market we will always get:
    • In the long run, perfectly competitive firms produce a level of output such that:
  • normal (zero) profit
  • P = minimum ATC
  • P = MC
  • Next lesson: Perfect Competition and Efficiency

8b - Allocative and Productive Efficiency in Perfectly Competitive Markets (econclassroom.com 19:35)
http://www.econclassroom.com/?p=3066
Why a firm in a perfectly competitive market will achieve allocative and productive efficiency in the long run.

Introduction

  • "In order to understand what makes less competitive markets inefficient, we first must understand what it is that makes perfectly competitive markets efficient."
  • Imperfectly competitive markets: monopoly, oligoply, monopolistic competition

Review

  • Productive efficiency:
    • productive efficiency is producing at the lowest cost
    • on a graph this is the lowest point on the ATC curve (minimum ATC)
    • this means the firm is using its resources wisely and not wasting any resources
    • "Productive efficiency occurs if the price of the good is equal to the minimum ATC"
    • ME: and, as we should already know, the MC curve crosses the ATC curve at the lowest point of the ATC, so we find the productively efficient quantity by finding the quantity where MC = ATC
  • Allocative Efficiency
    • when the quantity of output produced achieves the greatest level of total welfare (ME: satisfaction) possible
    • producing the quantity where the consumer and producer surplus is maximized
    • ME: producing the quantity where MSB = MSC (marginal social benefit = marginal social cost from chapters 3 and 5)
    • ME : producing the quantity that maximizes society's satisfaction
    • ME: producning more of what prople want and less of what they don't want (more music downloads and less CDs)

How Perfectly Competitve Marlkets achieve Productive Efficiency in the long Run

  • Productive efficiency:
    • productive efficiency is producing at the lowest cost
    • on a graph this is the lowest point on the ATC curve (minimum ATC)
    • this means the firm is using its resources wisely and not wasting any resources
    • "Productive efficiency occurs if the price of the good is equal to the minimum ATC"
    • ME: and, as we should already know, the MC curve crosses the ATC curve at the lowest point of the ATC, so we find the productively efficient quantity by finding the quantity where MC = ATC
    • firms achieve productive ifficiency if P = MC = ATC
  • On the graph of a perfectly competitive firm in long run equilibrium
    • the firm will produce the4 quantity where MR = MC because this is its profit maximizing quantity (Qf on the graph below)
    • and, we can see that the profit maximizing quantity is also the quantity where the ATC is at a minimum (Qf on the graph below)

      In the long run, perfectly competitive firms produce a level of output such that:

  • So, purely competitive firms will achieve productive efficiency in the long run
    • what would happen if the price was higher than ATC?
      • the frim would produce more
      • and the profit maximizing quantity will not be at the lowest point of the ATC curve; not where MC = ATC

        In the long run, perfectly competitive firms produce a level of output such that:

      • so, in the short run this firm is not productively efficient, but it is now earning economic profits
      • and as we learned in the previous video lecture, these profits will attract new firms, and because there are no barriers to entry, this will increase supply and decrease the price until each frim is again producing the quantity where the P = minimum ATC
      • and in the long run productive efficiency is achieved in perfectly competitive markets (P = minATC)

      In the long run, perfectly competitive firms produce a level of output such that:

How Perfectly Competitve Markets achieve Allocativetive Efficiency in the long Run

  • Allocative Efficiency
    • definition of allocative efficiency:
      • when the quantity of output produced achieves the greatest level of total welfare (ME: satisfaction) possible
      • producing the quantity where the consumer and producer surplus is maximized
      • ME: producing the quantity where MSB = MSC (marginal social benefit = marginal social cost from chapters 3 and 5)
      • ME : producing the quantity that maximizes society's satisfaction
      • ME: producning more of what prople want and less of what they don't want (more musinc downloads and less CDs)
  • consumer surplus (CS)
    • is the total well being of consumers who are willing and able to pay a higher price than the equilibrium price in the market
    • graphically consumer surplus is the area of the triangle below the demand curve and above the equilibrium price (the yellow area on the graph below)
  • producer surplus (PS)
    • is the total welfare of producers who are able to sell their product at a price greater than their cots of production
    • is the total welfare gained by producers who were able to sell their product a price higher than the price they were willing to accpt
    • graphically, producer wurplus is the area above the supply curve but below the equilibrium price (the blue traingle on the graph below)

      In the long run, perfectly competitive firms produce a level of output such that:

  • So, in long run equilibrium a perfectly competity market will produce the quantity where consumer and producer surplus is maximized and MSB = MSC
  • if less is produced (Q1)
    • we can see that MSB > MSC and this means too little is being produced
    • ME: I have use the terms MSB (marginal social benefit) and MSC (marginal social cost) , here the instructor is calling these just MB and MC
      • In the long run, perfectly competitive firms produce a level of output such that:
  • if more than the long run equilibrium quantity is produced (Q2):
    • MSB<MSC (video MC>MB) and society would be better off with less because the extra benefits that they are getting from one more unit of output is less than its costs
    • ME: remember that all costs are opportunity costs so if MSB<MSC this means that the costs to society of producing more are the lost benefits that we could have gotten if we produced something else. If MSC are high this means that something else would give us more satidsfaction.
    • and allocative efficiency is not achieved
  • So allocative efficiency is achived at that quantiy where MSB = MSC (MB = MC)
    • this is alo called the "socially optimal quantity"
  • For the individual firm (the graph on the right)
    • MSC = MC
    • MSB = P
    • so allocative efficiency is achieved where P=MC
    • ME: why is the price we have to pay for a product a benefit? Isn't that a cost?
      • price is a benefit to the consumer because it measure the benefits that the consumer is getting from the product
      • if consumersm who are part of society get a lot of benefits froma priduct they would be wiloing to pay more. If consumers get fr=ew benefits from a pridcut they would only buy it if the price was less
      • for example I would pay more to ski in the mountains of Colorado (where I am now as I type these notes) than I wouyld pay to ski the hill of Wisconsin because I get more benefits (more fun) skiing in Colorado
    • ME:We know that all firms what to maximize profits so they will produce the quantity where MR=MC. We can see on the graph below that this perfectly competitive firm in long run equilibrium will produce the quantity Qf to maximize its profits. But note that this is also where P=MC.. So even though all the firm was trying to do was to make as much money as possible it will firm also achieve allocative efficiency. This is the INVISIBLE HAND of competition that we talked about in chapter 2.

      In the long run, perfectly competitive firms produce a level of output such that:

  • SUMMARY: Competitive frims achieve allocative efficiency in the long run
    • All firms will produce the quantity where MR=MC to maximize theri profits
    • Because of the lack of barriers to entry, competitive firms will receive only normal profits in t he long run
    • But the long run profit maximizing quantity will also be the allocatively efficient quantity:
      • the quantity where P = MC,
      • the quantity where MSB = MSC
      • and the quantity where the sum of the consumer and producer surplus is maximized
  •  WHY?
    • perfectly competitive firms achieve allocative efficiency in the long run because the demand curve for the individual firm is perfectly price elastic
      • i.e. they are "price takers"
      • Since there are very many firms producing standardized (identical) products, firms do not have any control over the price of the product
      • this means that each individual firm can sell all they have at the market price
    • This means that the P = MR
      • since they don't have to lower thier pice to sell more
      • the extra revenue that they get when they sell one more is the same as the price
      • THEREFORE: when competitive firms try to find the quantity where MR=MC to maximize their profits, it will also be the quantity where P=MC. So when they maximize their profits they also achieve allocative efficiency
    • P = MR for perfectly competitive firms ONLY
      • we will see in other product market models that the P > MR, i.e. the price they receive is greater than the extra revenue (MR) they get when they sell one more
      • only for price takers with perfectly elastic demand curves does the P always equal MR
      • firms in other product market models must lower their price to sell more so, as we will see in future chapters P>MR
      • therefore, when firms in the other market models produce the quantity to maximize their profits (quantity where MR=MC, it will not be the allocatively efficient quantity (where P = MC).
  • To understand this better, let's see what happens if the competitive firms produce less than the profit maximizing quantity (Q1 on the graph below).
    •  at Q1 we can see that MR does not equal MC so the frim is not maximizing its proftis
    • in fact, we can see that ATC is greater than P , So TC will be greater than TR and the firm is l
    • earning a loss
    • ALSO, P > MC so there is an underallocation of resources toward this product. Too little is being produced. Remember, P measures the MSB and Mc measures the marginal social costs (assuminh that there are no externalities, so if P>MC then MSB>MSC and society would be happier with more.
    • Now if we assume that all firms are producing at Q1 on their individual cost curves then the market quantity being produced will also be less then the equilibrium. so on the market supply and demand graph Q1 would be produced, not the profit maximizing equilibrium quantity Qe.
    • At this smaller quantity the MB to consumers is greater than the MC
    • This is allocative inefficiency because society is getting less satisfaction
    • Using the consumer and producer surplus model:
      • allocative efficiency is achievced when the consumer andproducer surplus is maximized
      • this occurs at the equilibrium level of output

        In the long run, perfectly competitive firms produce a level of output such that:

      • but if the quantity is less than Qe, like Q1 then the total consumer plus producer surplus is less (see the green area on the graph below

        In the long run, perfectly competitive firms produce a level of output such that:

      • and there is a loss of satisfaction to society (less consumer and producer surplus) equal to the yellow triangle on the graph below. this is what economists call the "deadweight loss" of allocative inefficiency

        In the long run, perfectly competitive firms produce a level of output such that:

      • We Since less than the efficient quantity is being produced we say that resources are underallocated to this product, i.e. society would gain satisfaction (equal to the yellow triangle) if more resources were used so that more was produced. This is allocative inefficiency.
      • if firms produced more than the allocatively efficient (and profit maximizing) quantity then again we would have allocative inefficiiency. This time MC will be > P, and resources will be overallocated to the production of this product. Too much is being produced. Society would be happier if less of this was produced and more of something else that gives us more satisfaction.
        • in the market at Q2 on the graph below, MSB<MSC
        • ME: remember the opportunity cost (MSC) of consuming this product is the satisfaction that you are not getting from your next best alternative. So if extra benefits that you are getting from this product (MSB or D) is less than the benefits that you could get from something else (MSC or S) then society would be better off with less of this product. We say that resources are overallocated to the porduction of this product.

        In the long run, perfectly competitive firms produce a level of output such that:

Perfectly competitive firms achieve both productive and allocative efficiency in long run equilibrium

  • they will produce the profit maximizing quantity where MR=MC
  • and this quantity will also be the productively efficient quantity where ATC is at its minimum point
  • and, this quantity will also be allocatively efficient where P=MC

At what output level would a perfectly competitive firm produce?

The profit-maximizing choice for a perfectly competitive firm will occur at the level of output where marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost—that is, where MR = MC.

What is the perfectly competitive output?

A perfectly competitive firm can sell as large a quantity as it wishes, as long as it accepts the prevailing market price. If a firm increases the number of units sold at a given price, then total revenue will increase. If the price of the product increases for every unit sold, then total revenue also increases.