What consequence did the policy of mercantilism have for the british colonies in north america? *

journal article

British Mercantilism and the Economic Development of the Thirteen Colonies

The Journal of Economic History

Vol. 12, No. 2 (Spring, 1952)

, pp. 105-114 (10 pages)

Published By: Cambridge University Press

https://www.jstor.org/stable/2113218

Read and download

Log in through your school or library

Read Online (Free) relies on page scans, which are not currently available to screen readers. To access this article, please contact JSTOR User Support. We'll provide a PDF copy for your screen reader.

With a personal account, you can read up to 100 articles each month for free.

Get Started

Already have an account? Log in

Monthly Plan

  • Access everything in the JPASS collection
  • Read the full-text of every article
  • Download up to 10 article PDFs to save and keep
$19.50/month

Yearly Plan

  • Access everything in the JPASS collection
  • Read the full-text of every article
  • Download up to 120 article PDFs to save and keep
$199/year

Purchase a PDF

Purchase this article for $34.00 USD.

How does it work?

  1. Select the purchase option.
  2. Check out using a credit card or bank account with PayPal.
  3. Read your article online and download the PDF from your email or your account.

Journal Information

The Journal of Economic History is devoted to the multidisciplinary study of history and economics, and is of interest not only to economic historians but to social and demographic historians, as well as economists in general. The journal has broad coverage, in terms of both methodology and geographic scope. Topics covered include money and banking, trade, manufacturing, technology, transportation, industrial organisation, labour, agriculture, servitude, demography, education, economic growth, and the role of government and regulation. In addition, an extensive book review section keeps readers informed about the latest work in economic history and related fields. Instructions for Contributors at Cambridge Journals Online

Publisher Information

Cambridge University Press (www.cambridge.org) is the publishing division of the University of Cambridge, one of the world’s leading research institutions and winner of 81 Nobel Prizes. Cambridge University Press is committed by its charter to disseminate knowledge as widely as possible across the globe. It publishes over 2,500 books a year for distribution in more than 200 countries. Cambridge Journals publishes over 250 peer-reviewed academic journals across a wide range of subject areas, in print and online. Many of these journals are the leading academic publications in their fields and together they form one of the most valuable and comprehensive bodies of research available today. For more information, visit http://journals.cambridge.org.

Rights & Usage

This item is part of a JSTOR Collection.
For terms and use, please refer to our Terms and Conditions
The Journal of Economic History © 1952 Economic History Association
Request Permissions

Mercantilism is an economic theory and policy practised during Canada’s colonial periods. The theory of mercantilism holds that there is a fixed amount of wealth in the world. A nation’s wealth is thus dependent on exporting (selling to other countries) more than it imports (buying from others). European nations — including France and England (later Great Britain) — used this system to their advantage from the 16th century through the mid-19th century. The purpose was to extract as much wealth as possible from the colonies without investing much into them. The Atlantic slave trade is also inextricably linked to mercantilism. (See Black Enslavement in Canada.)

Mercantilism is an economic theory and policy practised during Canada’s colonial periods. The theory of mercantilism holds that there is a fixed amount of wealth in the world. A nation’s wealth is thus dependent on exporting (selling to other countries) more than it imports (buying from others). European nations — including France and England (later Great Britain) — used this system to their advantage from the 16th century through the mid-19th century. The purpose was to extract as much wealth as possible from the colonies without investing much into them. The Atlantic slave trade is also inextricably linked to mercantilism. (See Black Enslavement in Canada.)

Mercantilism in New France

Mercantilism developed as the primary economic model in New France (1534–1763). This model attempted to export as much wealth as possible out of Canada back to Europe for the least amount of investment. Because of this economic model, New France developed slowly compared with other European colonies in the Americas. Well into the mid-18th century, the colony’s population was a small fraction of the British Thirteen Colonies, even though the territory claimed by France was many times larger. The settlements of New France also had a significant gender imbalance, since nearly all the vocations in New France — such as soldiers and trappers — were held by men. (See Population Settlement of New France.)

This highlighted the differences between the policy of mercantilism and the political and religious interests of the French crown. The former focused on extracting wealth from Canada, while the latter wished to settle it. Cardinal Richelieu, France’s powerful Secretary of State for Commerce and the Marine, organized the Company of One Hundred Associates as a trading and colonization project. The company was granted an exclusive monopoly on the fur trade in New France. The company would fail by the mid-1660s, at which point New France became a province under France’s direct administration.

British Mercantilism

Like France, England also practised mercantilism, albeit not as strictly. England had a complex set of laws dating back to 1651 regulating shipping and trade. These were designed to establish military and economic supremacy, but also supported mercantilist economic policies. The Navigation Acts made the shipping and marketing of colonial goods the monopoly of England (later Great Britain); this helped England maintain a positive economic balance. The basic economic model — wherein colonies sent raw materials back to the European power — remained after Britain conquered New France during the Seven Years’ War (see The Conquest of New France).

Mercantilism was primarily intended to enrich European powers, though it also benefitted some colonists. Major fur traders of the late 18th century, like James McGill and Simon McTavish, gained immensely from their positions within the mercantilist economy. They exported furs to England (see Fur Trade in Canada) and imported goods from the Caribbean otherwise unavailable in British North America such as sugar, rum and cotton. While mercantilism provided protected markets that benefitted high-ranking colonial officials and other elites, the policy may have also hampered Canada’s early economic development. Canada became overly dependent on exporting certain key resources — or staples — rather than developing a more diversified economy or developing local industry.

In the early 20th century, economic historians Harold Innis and W.A. Mackintosh developed their Staple Thesis. They argued that this over-dependence on economic staples had a pervasive effect on the development of Canada’s economy, well beyond the era of mercantilism.

Hudson’s Bay Company

The Hudson’s Bay Company was a good example of a mercantilist corporation. The trading company was founded in 1670 to access the Canadian interior by way of Hudson Bay, rather than the St. Lawrence and Ottawa river valleys. The company was granted a monopoly by the English crown on trading rights in all the land whose rivers drained into Hudson Bay — an area that was known as Rupert’s Land until 1870. The Hudson’s Bay Company was predominantly focused on trapping beaver furs (see Fur Trading) to be sent back to England. It did little to develop permanent settlements in the Canadian interior.

Slavery

Critical to the success of this economic model was maximizing the value extracted from the colonies and maintaining a trade balance favourable to the European powers. In order to do so, the European powers were active participants in the transatlantic slave trade, enslaving people in Africa and taking them to work in European colonies.

France and England were actively involved in slavery from the 16th century until the early 19th century. The labour of enslaved people was used to pick cotton or harvest sugar, which was then sent back to Europe. Those goods were then converted into consumer products. Though this kind of plantation slavery was not typically practised in Canada, enslaved people were exploited in other ways as part of New France’s and British North America’s colonial economies (see Black Enslavement in Canada). The enslavement of Indigenous people by Europeans was also common during both the French and British colonial periods.  Enslaved people were used in a variety of labour roles and economic activities, including the fur trade, where they either assisted traders or were traded for furs.

End of Mercantilism

Mercantilism fell out of favour as an economic theory beginning in the late 18th century. The repeal of the Corn Laws and the Navigation Acts in the mid-19th century permanently ended mercantilist practices in the British Empire. Mercantilism was sharply criticized by philosopher and economist Adam Smith in his seminal treatise, The Wealth of Nations, which is now considered a cornerstone of classical economics.

Canada’s population grew rapidly after the American Revolution (see Loyalists in Canada; Black Loyalists in British North America). Immigration brought a large settler population of farmers, craftsmen and artisans whose economic activity largely fell outside of mercantilism. As opposed to previously, British authorities were now keen to invest in the development of Canada to prevent an American invasion. As the 19th century progressed, there was a need for more diversified local economic activity (such as the processing of raw agricultural products into food, construction, manufacturing of household goods, etc.). While Canada continued exporting economic staples back to the United Kingdom (and elsewhere), it also began exporting manufactured goods. Major infrastructure projects of the 19th century — such as the building of railways, bridges and canals — stimulated the development of heavy industry in Canada. As the population grew, the economy became increasingly diversified and better suited to local needs. In the process, Canada’s economy was transformed from its mercantilist origins into the capitalist economy of the modern period.

What is mercantilism and how did it affect early colonial life in North America?

In the context of the European colonization of North America, mercantilism refers to the idea that colonies existed for the benefit of the Mother Country. In other words, the British saw the American colonists as tenants who 'paid rent' by providing materials for Britain to use.

How did the British colonies in America support the policy of mercantilism?

Mercantilism was a popular economic philosophy in the 17th and 18th centuries. In this system, the British colonies were moneymakers for the mother country. The British put restrictions on how their colonies spent their money so that they could control their economies.

What was the effect of mercantilism?

What were the effects of mercantilism? Mercantilism led to the creation of monopolistic trading companies, such as the East India Company and the French East India Company. Restrictions on where finished goods could be purchased led in many cases to burdensome high prices for those goods.