When demand is elastic and supply is inelastic the burden of tax falls mainly on consumers?

Tax incidence

The relative burden, or incidence, of an indirect tax is determined by the price elasticity of demand (PED) of the consumer in response to a price rise. If the consumer is unresponsive, and PED is inelastic, the burden will fall mainly on the consumer. However, if the consumer is responsive to the price rise, and PED is elastic, the burden will fall mainly on the firm.

Tax burden on the consumer

When demand is inelastic the tax burden is mainly on the consumer.

When demand is elastic and supply is inelastic the burden of tax falls mainly on consumers?

Tax burden on producer

When demand is elastic, the tax burden is mainly on the producer.

When demand is elastic and supply is inelastic the burden of tax falls mainly on consumers?

Tax burden evenly split

In this case, the tax burden is split evenly between the consumer and producer.

When demand is elastic and supply is inelastic the burden of tax falls mainly on consumers?

Example – the incidence of a tax on cigarettes

If a government puts a £1 tax on each packet of cigarettes, the legal incidence is on the cigarette smoker. However, the local market may have many sellers, and be highly competitive. This means that a retailer, fearing they will lose sales, may decide to put up the price by only 50p, and pay the balance of 50p to the government themselves. In this case, the economic incidence is shared because both are worse off.

When demand is elastic and supply is inelastic the burden of tax falls mainly on consumers?

The smoker is worse off because of the price increase of 20p, and the seller is worse off because 10p must come out of their revenue to pay the government.

Test your knowledge with a quiz


Press Next to launch the quiz
You are allowed two attempts – feedback is provided after
each question is attempted.

Type your learning objectives here.

  • Explain how the elasticity of demand and supply determine the incidence of a tax on buyers and
    sellers

Example

Elasticity also reveals whether firms can pass higher costs that they incur on to consumers. Addictive substances tend to fall into this category. For example, the demand for cigarettes is relatively inelastic among regular smokers who are somewhat addicted; economic research suggests that increasing the price of cigarettes by 10% leads to about a 3% reduction in the quantity of cigarettes smoked by adults, so the elasticity of demand for cigarettes is 0.3. If society increases taxes on companies that make cigarettes, the result will be, as in Figure 3.14 that the supply curve shifts from S0 to S1. However, as the equilibrium moves from E0 to E1, these taxes are mainly passed along to consumers in the form of higher prices. These higher taxes on cigarettes will raise tax revenue for the government, but they will not much affect the quantity of smoking.

When demand is elastic and supply is inelastic the burden of tax falls mainly on consumers?

Figure 3.14

If the goal is to reduce the quantity of cigarettes demanded, it must be achieved by shifting this inelastic demand back to the left, perhaps with public programs to discourage the use of cigarettes or to help people to quit. For example, anti-smoking advertising campaigns have shown some ability to reduce smoking. However, if demand for cigarettes was more elastic, as in Figure 3.15, then an increase in taxes that shifts supply from S0 to S1 and equilibrium from E0 to E1 would reduce the quantity of cigarettes smoked substantially. Youth smoking seems to be more elastic than adult smoking—that is, the quantity of youth smoking will fall by a greater percentage than the quantity of adult smoking in response to a given percentage increase in price.

When demand is elastic and supply is inelastic the burden of tax falls mainly on consumers?

Figure 3.15

Incidence of Tax

The example of cigarette taxes showed that because demand is inelastic, taxes are not effective at reducing the equilibrium quantity of smoking, and they are mainly passed along to consumers in the form of higher prices. The analysis, or manner, of how the burden of a tax is divided between consumers and producers is called tax incidence. Typically, the incidence, or burden, of a tax falls both on the consumers and producers of the taxed good. But if one wants to predict which group will bear most of the burden, all one needs to do is examine the elasticity of demand and supply. In the tobacco example, the tax burden falls on the most inelastic side of the market. If demand is more inelastic than supply, consumers bear most of the tax burden, and if supply is more inelastic than demand, sellers bear most of the tax burden. The intuition for this is simple. When the demand is inelastic, consumers are not very responsive to price changes, and the quantity demanded remains relatively constant when the tax is introduced. In the case of smoking, the demand is inelastic because consumers are addicted to the product. The government can then pass the tax burden along to consumers in the form of higher prices, without much of a decline in the equilibrium quantity.

Similarly, when a tax is introduced in a market with an inelastic supply, such as, for example, beachfront hotels, and sellers have no alternative than to accept lower prices for their business, taxes do not greatly affect the equilibrium quantity. The tax burden is now passed on to the sellers. If the supply was elastic and sellers had the possibility of reorganizing their businesses to avoid supplying the taxed good, the tax burden on the sellers would be much smaller. The tax would result in a much lower quantity sold instead of lower prices received.

In Figure 3.16, the supply is inelastic and the demand is elastic, such as in the example of beachfront hotels. While consumers may have other vacation choices, sellers can’t easily move their businesses. By introducing a tax, the government essentially creates a wedge between the price paid by consumers Pc and the price received by producers Pp. In other words, of the total price paid by consumers, part is retained by the sellers and part is paid to the government in the form of a tax. The distance between Pc and Pp is the tax rate. The new market price is Pc, but sellers receive only Pp per unit sold, as they pay Pc-Pp to the government. Since a tax can be viewed as raising the costs of production, this could also be represented by a leftward shift of the supply curve, where the new supply curve would intercept the demand at the new quantity Qt. For simplicity, Figure 5.10 omits the shift in the supply curve.

When demand is elastic and supply is inelastic the burden of tax falls mainly on consumers?

Figure 3.16 – Elastic Demand and Inelastic Supply

The tax revenue is given by the shaded area, which is obtained by multiplying the tax per unit by the total quantity sold Qt. The tax incidence on the consumers is given by the difference between the price paid Pc and the initial equilibrium price Pe. The tax incidence on the sellers is given by the difference between the initial equilibrium price Pe and the price they receive after the tax is introduced Pp. In Figure 3.16, the tax burden falls disproportionately on the sellers, and a larger proportion of the tax revenue (the shaded area) is due to the resulting lower price received by the sellers than by the resulting higher prices paid by the buyers. The example of the tobacco excise tax could be described by Figure 3.17 where the supply is more elastic than demand. The tax incidence now falls disproportionately  on consumers, as shown by the large difference between the price they pay, Pc, and the initial equilibrium price, Pe. Sellers receive a lower price than before the tax, but this difference is much smaller than the change in consumers’ price.

When demand is elastic and supply is inelastic the burden of tax falls mainly on consumers?

Figure 3.17 – Elastic Supply and Inelastic Demand

From this analysis one can also predict whether a tax is likely to create a large revenue or not. The more elastic the demand curve, the easier it is for consumers to reduce quantity instead of paying higher prices. The more elastic the supply curve, the easier it is for sellers to reduce the quantity sold, instead of taking lower prices. In a market where both the demand and supply are very elastic, the imposition of an excise tax generates low revenue. Excise taxes tend to be thought to hurt mainly the specific industries they target. For example, the medical device excise tax, in effect since 2013, has been controversial for it can delay industry profitability and therefore hamper start-ups and medical innovation. But ultimately, whether the tax burden falls mostly on the medical device industry or on the patients depends simply on the elasticity of demand and supply.

When demand is elastic and supply is inelastic the burden of a tax falls mainly on consumers True or false?

The wedge between the demand price and supply price becomes the government's tax revenue. When the price elasticity of demand is low and the price elasticity of supply is high, the burden of an excise tax falls mainly on consumers.

When supply inelastic and demand is elastic What is the tax incidence falls on?

When supply is inelastic and demand is elastic, the tax incidence falls on the producer. When supply is elastic and demand is inelastic, the tax incidence falls on the consumer.

When elasticity of demand and elasticity of supply are equal the burden of tax?

Tax incidence can also be related to the price elasticity of supply and demand. When supply is more elastic than demand, the tax burden falls on the buyers. If demand is more elastic than supply, producers will bear the cost of the tax.

What happens when demand is inelastic and elastic?

If demand is elastic: • A given percentage rise in price brings a larger percentage decrease in the quantity demanded. And total revenue decreases. If demand is inelastic: • A given percentage rise in price brings a smaller percentage decrease in the quantity demanded. And total revenue increases.